5/02/2014

Discover Quality Change of U.S Postsecondary Institutions from 1990 to 2010 (lit review)



      In terms of higher education, there is little consensus on how to measure or even define quality because the output (students’ achievement) depends on both schools’ productivity and students’ ability. Cheng and Tam (1997) concluded that education quality is a vague and controversial concept because numerous sources of revenues and influential impacts of universities entail that there are a large number of stakeholders, all of whom have their own notions of good quality. For example, faculty members might consider lighter teaching loads and more capable students as positive signs of a good college while coaches of varsity teams might think that a good college should be able to attract promising athlete-students. As Green (1994) rightly put, it is meaningless to talk about quality unless we have a clear criteria about context and stakeholders.
      Quality of higher education is difficult to measure due to various dimensions of educational products. Like a manufacturing firm, universities are a system of independent components that work together to achieve certain goals. Among different goals set by schools, one consensus is that schools should produce good students. Theoretically, the best method to assess what college education bestows on students should be value added measure, namely that we test capabilities of students before and after graduation and infer the difference as a consequence of college education. This method, however, is hard to carry through because capabilities are manifold and sometimes subtle to assess[1]. What’s worse, some consequences of an institution may take years to get observed, and as time goes by it is difficult to decide whether college education is the major cause.
      A second method is output measure, namely that we find out the outcomes of a college education by tracing lifetime performance of graduates of a particular college. A lot of previous researches use student income as proxy of performance but their findings are mixed. Brewer, Eide and Ehrenberg (1996), using data from National Longitudinal of the High School Class of 1972 and High School and Beyond, found that after controlling for selection effects, attending elite private institutions entails significant economic returns. Similarly, Black, Daniel and Smith (2005) discovered that earning effects of college quality is economically important and stable for men and women. However, Dale and Krueger (2002) used College and Beyond survey and found that graduates of selective institutions, except those from low-income family, earn about the same as those with comparable abilities from less selective ones.
      Another method is called input measure, whose punch line is that we infer quality of an institution based on quality of its inputs. Typical inputs of an institution consist of student body, faculty members, financial resources, etc. By examining inputs, we can know a school’s expenditure per student, selectivity of students and capability of faculty members, which are all important ingredients for providing good students. Input measure is widely used due to abundance of data, namely U.S Department of Education’s The Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System (IPEDS). This approach assumes that better resources translate into better education for students.
      Considering that most postsecondary institutions in US are not-for-profit organizations, it is normally unreasonable to assume that they have an incentive to be cautious about using inputs. However, one justification for this approach is that higher education market is competitive. Based on classical economic theory, heightened competition incentivizes market participants to allocate inputs more efficiently to stay in the game. Black, Daniel and Smith (2005) used input measure and found that quality of colleges has more impact on graduates than that of secondary and high schools. They conjectured this was because higher education market is more competitive. More convincing evidence is provided by Hoxby (1997), who found that since 1940 the market for baccalaureate education, transformed from a collection of local autarkies to nationally integrated, has become significantly more competitive.
      This paper defines quality as an institution’s dedication to instruction because it is the key ingredient of producing good students, which is mutually agreed as one core mission of higher education. For research institutions, I will additionally include research expenditure as an indicator. Some economists (Getz and Siegfried, 1991) criticized the reasoning that research effort induces higher quality of college education is flawed because it begs the question that the main purpose of higher education is to impart frontier knowledge to average undergraduate students. However, I think that their argument is outdated. Undergraduate students have been more and more involved in research projects as research assistants, and some reports (Sabatini, 1997, Russell, Hancock and McCullough, 2007) showed that students benefit from having more communication with faculty members and are more likely to pursue higher degrees after graduations.
      To find out how quality has changed for different types of postsecondary institutions (i.e. private research universities, private bachelor colleges, public research universities and community colleges) from 1990 to 2010, I will study their expenditure profiles, use regression to discover to what extent does quality related expenditure drive up the total expenditure, and draw inferences of quality change with respect to education. Private for-profit universities are not included for two reasons. Firstly, most for-profit universities have a short history of existence and their financial reports are incomplete, which makes it impossible to see their trend of spending. What’s more, for-profit institutions have different organizational structures and goals from non-profit peers, and we need to come up with a new model to study them, which is beyond the scope of this paper. 

References:

1.        Cheng, Y. C. and Tam, W. M. “Multi-models of Quality in Education,” Quality Assurance in Education, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp.22-31, 1997
2.                 Green, D. What is Quality in Higher Education? Buckingham: SRHE and Open University Press, 1994
3.          Brewer, Dominic, Eric Eide and Ronald Ehrenberg. “Does It Pay to Attend an Elite Private College? Cross-cohort evidence on the effects of college type on earnings.” The Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 34, No. 1, Winter 1999, pp. 104-123
4.           Black, Dan, Kermit Daniel and Jeffrey Smith. “College Quality and Wages in the United States.” German Economic Review 2005, pp. 415-443
5.             Dale, Stacy and Alan Krueger, “Estimating the Return to College Selectivity over the Career Using Administrative Earning Data.” NBER Working paper No. 17159,  June 2011
6.             Hoxby, Caroline. “How the Changing Market Structure of U.S. Higher Education Explains College Tuition,” NBER Working paper No. 6323, 1997
 




[1] The output of higher education includes many intangible elements that escape formal valuation in markets (for example, self-esteem, friendship, maturation, etc.). In fact, so many of the services of higher education cannot be measured in physical terms that it is impossible to get a good approximation of their value.

No comments:

Post a Comment