Since the 2008 financial meltdown, there have been a lot of debates
and discussions on what happened and what should be done to check the next
financial crisis. The book Crisis Economics by professor Nouriel
Roubini, nicknamed Dr. Doom due to his bearish economic view, and journalist
Stephen Mihm, contains review of the 2008 crisis and pro-regulation suggestions
to fix the market.
The central thesis of Crisis Economics is that financial
crises are inherent in capitalism and predictable1. After a recap of
significant financial crises in history, they claimed that they found patterns
of a typical financial crisis. In their model, a financial crisis starts with
an asset bubble, which results from excessive credit supply or optimism about
one technological innovation. Believing that asset price will never go down,
investors borrow more and buy more. At some point, the bubble implodes, sending
some highly leveraged investors to bankruptcy. Creditors realize the problem of
bad loans and demand investors to put up more funds and collateral to
compensate for falling price, which incentivizes them to fire sell the asset. A
sudden increase in asset supply drives down price further and stirs panics in
the market. More and more investors default, and banks are unwilling to loan
out. As a result, liquidity crunches and crisis occurs.
This model seems compelling, but it doesn’t elaborate a couple of
important aspects. First, where does excessive credit supply come from? A lax
regulation of government or a loose monetary policy by Fed? If this is the
case, can we blame market for being greedy? Besides, just because it is cheaper
for investors to get credits doesn’t necessarily mean that people will demand a
whole lot of them. In other words, what the authors missed in their model is a
discussion of elasticity of credit demand curve. In addition, what is the
crucial turning point? The authors just said that we could use various economic
indicators to discern the turning point, but they didn’t articulate how to do
the prediction. It is easy to deduce what would happen after bubble implosion,
but predicting the timing of bust is a totally different issue. In my opinion,
this lack of discussion attenuates their argument that financial crises are
predictable.
In the next couple of chapters, the authors turned to analyze the
financial meltdown in 2008. They claimed that lots of parties were culpable for
the crisis. Considering that the reasons are manifold, I will first lay out
their arguments, and then present what other economists think and my thoughts.
Alan Greenspan’s monetary policies
In the book, Alan Greenspan was blamed for adopting an easy-money
policy by keeping interest rate too low for too long, which help expand the
credit, incentivize irresponsible investment and foster the housing bubble.2
But some economists argue that
Greenspan’s policy was actually tight and that critics made a classic mistake for
using interest rates to evaluate monetary policy. 3 After a check of
monetary base during Greenpan’s period, economist David Henderson found out
that the inflation rate was stable and the change between the amount and
velocity of M2 coincided with scenarios within a free banking system.4 In
other words, though the interest rate during Greenspan’s era was low, it didn’t
necessarily inject a huge amount of money in the housing market and start the bubble.
In defend of his actions, Greenspan was actually right in attributing the low
interest rate to a massive flow of savings from Asian economies and Latin
America5. One problem of Crisis Economics is that the authors
didn’t mention much statistical measure of monetary bases. Layman readers thus
are very easy to be frightened by the unusually low interest rate and guided to
believe that money and credit exploded during Greenspan’s period.
Payment mechanism in Wall Street
Roubini and Mihm criticized that big bonuses in Wall Street
incentivize bankers to take more risks and higher leverage on a massive scale6.
Similarly, celebrities like President Obama and vice president Biden considered
big bonuses as “shameful irresponsibility”. However, such fury might have
missed the target. Economist Alan Reynold explained that those big figure
bonuses were actually paid to a large number of employees within the Commerce
Department’s North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) rather than
merely high-profile investment bankers7.
In addition, a second thought may justify such compensation
mechanism. Bonuses, different from fixed salaries, are variable costs for banks
doing business in financial industry known for its high volatility. Paying big
bonuses and not-that-big salaries does two good things for banks. First, it
keeps them from having to predict the future. Instead of having to budget money
for all employee pay in at the start of the year, managers can look back at the
end of year, figure out what final revenues are, and set pay levels
accordingly. Such payment strategy limits the risk of over or underpaying to
employees. A widely ignored fact was
that after the financial crisis, many Wall Street firms didn’t cut employees’
overall pay by much; instead, they shrank the cash portion of bonuses and paid
more in salaries to compensate for the missing bonuses.8
Another advantage of this payment system is that it makes banks
easier to cut variable costs very quickly when necessary. When the chips are
down, cutting bonuses instead of salaries means that the firms don’t have to
lay off too many employees. Recently, increased regulation of employee bonuses
compensation has triggered increasing salaries and led to a higher proportion
of deferred compensation levels, leading to a concerning highly fixed cost base
for a volatile revenue business.
As for the argument that big bonuses encourage reckless behavior by
incentivizing traders to swing for the fences in an effort to juice their own
pay, theoretically a bonus-based compensation system should actually reduce the
risk of bad behavior, as bonuses can claw back when something goes horribly
wrong. What’s more, a recent research conducted by Cheng, Raina and Xiong
showed out that mid-level securitization agents were unaware of the danger of
housing sectors since they also bought a lot in housing market.9 In
other words, the reasoning presented by Roubini and Mihm can at most partially
explain the over-issuance of toxic securities. In this case, changing the
payment system might not check the occurrence of the next financial crisis.
Ownerships and sizes of investment banks
Roubini and Mihm believed that huge principle-agent problems within
the investment banks partly led to over-issuance of securities of bad quality. Shareholders
didn’t have much incentive to monitor the banking business because firms relied
on borrowed money for operations so heavily that shareholders didn’t have much
skin in the game.10 They doubted that managers could manage big and
complicated investment banks and suggested that it was a disaster to allow
investment banks to go public in 1970s. As a remedy, they called for a more
responsible mechanism, namely partnership, to incentivize shareholders to
monitor their firms’ business.11
Roubini and Mihm were right that investment banks should have more
capital for cushioning the possible liquidity shock, but turning investment
banks back to partnership might not be the best way. Back in 1998 when Goldman
Sachs decided to go public, some economists had guessed that the decision was a
response to technological change and competitors’ expansions.12 Research
later conducted by Morrison and Wilhelm Jr. confirmed the previous conjecture. They
discovered that that advances in information technology (especially the fast
development of computer technology since the late 1960s) and codification of
tacit human capital in financial services increased the cost for investment
banks to maintain partnerships and incentivized them to go public to expand and
enjoy benefit of economies of scales.13 From this perspective,
forcing investment banks back to partnership may result in unintended
consequences like diseconomies of scales.
One suggestion Roubini and Mihm gave was to break up banks that are
“too big to fail”.14 They reasoned that the collapse of Lehman
Brothers and the resulting panic of financial market showed that some financial
institutions had become so big and interconnected that their collapse would
cause systemic effects. 15 But some economists present their worry
and doubt about such radical move. Peter J. Wallison thought that the idea of
too big to fail is at best a plausible theory. 16 The collapse of
Lehman Brothers didn’t drag down any other financial firms. None of the
institutions rescued after Lehman—Wachovia, WaMu, and AIG—were made insolvent
or unstable or had to be rescued because of exposure to Lehman.17 Historical
evidence revealed that unless the market is already in a panic, with many firms
insolvent, the notion of too big to fail lead regulators to overreact. Besides,
breaking up big banks may lead to big consequences like lack of diversification
of risks and renegotiations of financial contracts. Breaking up big banks may
not necessarily be a bad idea, but without a complete cost-benefit analysis the
unintended costs may jeopardize the whole financial market.
Problems of credit rating agencies (CRAs)
Roubini and Mihm were critical of the role CRAs played in the
financial crisis. They criticized CRAs for taking hefty fees from issuers of
securities and letting toxic derivatives flow to the market. They called for a
complete reform in rating system, namely that CRAs should be forbidden to offer
any consulting or modeling services, more agencies should be allowed to
evaluate the derivatives, and change in payment systems.18
I agree with the authors that more competition should be introduced
in credit evaluation business. Historically, regulators have been using credit
evaluation to oversee the financial market. During Great Depression, the Office
of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) stipulated that banks not obtaining
credit evaluation would be panelized, which introduced CRAs into financial regulation
framework. In 1970s, regulators set up Nationally Recognized Statistical Rating
Organization (NRSRO) to oversee the ever-increasing volume of securitization. Issuers
of securities have to obtain rating from NRSRO in order to maintain the
operation. This legislation was intended to help investors understanding the
underlying risks of various derivatives, but for NRSRO members (S&P,
Moody’s and Fitch), lack of competition led to oligarchic profits, which
incentivized them to produce worse services. Credit ratings were severely
inaccurate in the incidences of WorldCom, Enron, Parmalat and 2008 financial
crisis, and it is hard to believe these are just random errors of CRAs. 19
However, NRSRO CRAs’ fees and profitability increased during 2002 and
2008. 20 This implies that government-granted oligarchy in credit
rating business has skewed initial objective as to provide accurate
information; instead, issuers pay CRAs in order to issue the derivatives. In my
opinion, introducing more competition can incentivize CRAs to develop better
models to evaluate the bonds and stocks, and issuers can have more freedom
choosing CRAs that provide better services.
“Deregulation” of financial sector
The authors’ argument on deregulation is in fact a widely accepted
narrative why 2008 financial crisis. They attributed the cause to the repeal of
Glass-Steagall Act and the failure to regulate the shadow banking systems,
which incentivized excessive financial innovations like credit default swaps. (CDSs)
I think it hilarious that authors argue that regulation was weak. Financial sector
is the most regulated sector in America. Any responsible banking textbook would
list page-long regulation implemented. During the so-called “free banking” era
banks had to observe strict rules. Even the Glass-Steagall Act is only
partially repealed: banks are still prohibited from underwriting or dealing
with securities (Section 16) and securities firms cannot take deposits (Section
21). 21 Roubini and Mihm proposed that investment banks should be
regulated like commercial banks and have access to deposit insurance, but I
strongly oppose to this idea. Regulation is supposed to protect depositors from
bad loans, but it is meant to protect commercial bank investors. Investors of
securities should bear cost by themselves rather than rely on the lender of
last resort. What’s worse, the new legislations are often superimposed on the
current regulation mechanism, leading to massive overlapping and waste of
resources.
As for the argument that fancy derivatives sprouted in lieu of
loose regulation, I would say the opposite. The regulation has been strong over
time, and to gain profit, firms have to figure out other ways to gain profits.
Offshore banking emerges for regulatory arbitrage and rent seeking abounds
because of tight regulation on branching and banking business. The regulation
record is disastrous, but it seems that every time a crisis occurs, people long
for another piece of law with no scrutiny of what the real cause is in the
first place.
Roubini and Mihm criticized that collapse of CDSs led to market
crisis, but such claim is questionable. Lehman Brothers was the biggest CDS
player, but its bankruptcy didn’t drag down many of its counterparties. Nor did
many firms it guaranteed CDSs for defaulted during the crisis. As for AIG,
although most of its CDSs were written to guarantee the CDOs backed by MBS that
were backed by toxic assets, it screwed up mainly because it didn’t hedge risk
when writing swaps, which was a rather unusual case. Since most of the CDOs AIG
was covering had lost value during the crisis and it didn’t sufficient
collaterals to pay the counterparties, its bankruptcy would jeopardize market.
However, considering that the obligation of the CDSs was between 25 and 41
billion, it might not cause systemic risk, which was the reason why the Fed
bailed out AIG. 22 The two incidents might imply that CDSs are not
as dangerous as many people assumed, but can we actually find out a way to make
them safer? The authors discussed about the idea of having these fancy
derivatives traded in a central clearinghouses.23 Clearinghouses can
mandate member banks to put in collaterals, assume the burden of the contracts
if counterparty failed. But the authors’ worries were that clearinghouses might
fail and investment banks would come up with other ways to avoid
clearinghouses’ requirement. Some other economists have proposed some
supplement strategies. Jeremy Kress argued that central clearinghouses should
have access to emergency credit from central bank. 24 (My worry
about this proposal is moral hazard.) Professor Rizzo thinks that bailing out
central clearinghouse would be easier than bailing out multiple individual
banks. Peter J. Wallison worries about the potential cost for clearinghouse to
oversee the CDS trading. 25
Conclusion
One big impression I feel about Crisis Economics is that it
is a book from the perspective of legislators. Roubini and Mihm seem to have a
craving for legislation and additional regulation. Though they endorse the
thinking by acknowledging that a necessary reckoning must take place over the
longer term in order to achieve a return to prosperity26, throughout
the book I could only read recommendations for more government intervention and
the notion that financial sector cannot correct itself, and it seems their
mention of Austrian School thoughts was just a superficial courtesy to
historical figures.
One problem I find in this book is the shortage of footnotes,
making it hard to trace his sources and cross-match them with their arguments.
What’s worse, the book is filled with non-innovative and costly solutions to
fixing the financial system. I’m not saying that financial market shouldn’t be
regulated. My point is that, given that there are already a lot of regulations
overlapping one with another, superimposition of another piece of legislation
might not be valuable. The causes of the 2008 financial crisis remains a puzzle
for me, but some ideas that the authors presented can be excluded after a
cross-matching of historical data and researches.
Overall, Crisis Economics is an easy-reading introductory
book about what happened in 2008 financial market. However, I’m disappointed about
this book because it doesn’t provide many refreshing thoughts and convincing
evidence.
References and citations
1.
Nouriel Roubini and Stephen Mihm, Crisis
Economics, (Penguin Books Ltd, 2010) pp19
2.
Ibid, pp33
3.
David R. Henderson and Jeffery
Rogers Hummel, “Greenspan’s Monetary Policy in Retrospect”, Cato Institute,
November 3, 2008
4.
Ibid
5.
Diego Valderrama, “Are Global
Imbalances Due to Financial Under development of Emerging Economies?” Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter no. 2008-12, April 12, 2008, Alan
Greenspan, The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a new world,(New York,
Penguin Press, 2007), pp385-388
6.
Nouriel Roubini and Stephen Mihm, Crisis
Economics, (Penguin Books Ltd, 2010) pp69
7.
Alan Reynolds, “The Truth About
Those Billion Bonus”, Forbes, February 10, 2009
8.
Kevin Roose, “In Defense of Wall
Street Bonuses”, NY Times, December 12, 2012
9.
Ing-Haw Cheng, Sahil Raina, and Wei
Xiong, “Wall Street and the Housing Bubble”, National Bureau of Economic
Research, March 2013
10. Nouriel
Roubini and Stephen Mihm, Crisis Economics, (Penguin Books Ltd, 2010) pp70
11. Ibid,
pp197
12. James
Suroweicki, “Why Do Investment Banks Go Public”, Slate website, June 19, 1998
13. Alan
D. Morrison and William J. Wilhelm, Jr., “The Demise of Investment-Banking Partnerships:
Theory and Evidence”, Oxford Financial Research Centre Working Paper, July 2004
14. Nouriel
Roubini and Stephen Mihm, Crisis Economics, (Penguin Books Ltd, 2010) pp223
15. Ibid
16. Peter
J. Wallison, “Breaking Up the Big Banks: Is Anybody Thinking?”, American
Enterprise Institute, September 18, 2012
17. Ibid
18. Nouriel
Roubini and Stephen Mihm, Crisis Economics, (Penguin Books Ltd, 2010)
pp195-19
19. Claire A. Hill, “Why Did Anyone Listen to the Rating
Agencies after Enron?”, Journal of Business and Technology Law, Vol. 4, pp283,
2009
20. P. Jenkins, “DBRS to Challenge Big Agencies,” Financial Times
(London), January 10, 2006
21. Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, Public Law 106-102, U.S. Statutes at Large
113 (1999): 1338.
22. Peter
J. Wallison, “Deregulation and Financial Crisis: An Urban Myth”, American
Enterprise Institute, October, 2009
23. Nouriel
Roubini and Stephen Mihm, Crisis Economics, (Penguin Books Ltd, 2010)
pp201
24. Jeremy
C. Kress, “Credit Default Swap, Clearinghouse, and Systemic Risk: Why
Centralized Counterparties Must Have Access To Central Bank Liquidity”, Harvard
Journal of Legislation, Vol. 48
25. Peter
J. Wallison, “Unnecessary Intervention: The Administration’s Effort to Regulate
Credit Default Swap”, American Enterprise Institute, August, 2009
26. Peter J. Wallison, “Does Shadow Banks Need Regulation?”, American
Enterprise Institute, May-June 2012
No comments:
Post a Comment